Saturday, August 22, 2009

How much should a person consume?


This is a book review that is not objective. My personal views are in there!

How much should a person consume?

A statement (by it self) contentious to the core! I am not sure exactly why Ramchanda Guha choose it to be the best suited title, but it was definitely one of the main points this books raises for discussion.

A little about Ramchandra Guha before I proceed. Padma Bhusan, Foreign Policy Magazine’s Top 100 Intellectuals, brilliant writer, incisive debater on CNN-IBN, IIM-C alumnus, rational environmentalist (if he is, I think so), objective historian, PhD dissertation on social history of Indian forests, columnist with Teleghaph and Hindu, definitely good looking, etc. Not necessarily in the order I have listed. Wikipedia him. Else: http://www.charlierose.com/guest/view/6243.

The book begins with a quote by Eugene O’Neill, “…condemned to be one of those who has to see all sides of a question….” Guha has succeeded in seeing many sides if not all of environmentalist movements. Contrasting environmentalism in US and India, he highlights the similarities and the clear class and thought distinction in the movement’s resting place within these parts of the globe.

The chapter uno begins with defining “disciplinary chauvinism,” which most of us suffer from to some extent. To me an ‘air pollution researcher’ (put simply) environment is mostly about how clear the view is when I look at downtown LA from my lab window. Whether I can see the Hollywood sign or the San Gabriels, and the manifestations of when all this is not visible. Basically, my environmentalism, apart from nature and wilderness appreciation, is an environmental degradation problem for which an engineered solution can be strived. That is what keeps me in business. Environmentalism to me doesn’t mean “Narmada Bachao,” which I think is a amalgamation of taking a confused high moral ground to block the ebb and flow of economic evolution spurred by an instinct to be a savior disguised under ecological paradigms!, more than environmentalism. (I do agree with them on some ecological points, but there is always a price to pay!) Environmentalism is to each its own, air and water belongs to all (not equally anymore), but I picked up this book to understand what environmentalism is in other forms and how to put it in context of economics.

This takes us to chapter 3 where the author discusses three environmental utopias as imagined by different genres of environmentalists, in context of environmental history - Primitivism (wilderness movement, nature’s right to exist as in of itself), Agrarianism (social justice, peoples rights to yield sustainably) and Scientific Industrialism (progress and policy guided by experts). He further discusses the ‘biocentric’ and ‘anthroprocentic’ attitudes. In all, this chapter is an excellent introduction to various genres of environmentalists.

Chapter 2, 4 and 5 [The Indian Road to Sustainability, Democracy in the Forest, Authoritarianism in the Wild] discuss the various environment movements in India. As always the author has succeeded in putting the history of the movements and the personalities involved in succinct but appropriately detailed manner. You would come to appraise the idea – agrarianism environmentalism, the dominant philosophy in Indian context. Chapter 4 goes into the history of state forestry in India and examined the models success, more so socially. I believe the economic tragedy of Indian forests is well known. Discussing the fallout of authoritarianism in Chapter 5, I thought the success stories of such reserves were amiss. The chapter focused on the creation of ecological refugees by “green missionaries”. It can certainly be the dominant thought for a sociologist, however looking at it from a holistic point of view, since we are not living in a world with isolated societies or clusters in our small reserves; and more often than we want choices made in one affect the other. Thus, there is a price to bear for preserving exotic species for posterity and that price is often unjust to those who are on the same side as wildlife preservers. The plight of tribals evicted from reserves is a negative externality of the way our societies have evolved, and so is ‘Authoritarianism in the Wild.’ However, Guha succeeds in these chapters in not only asking the right questions but also answering them.

Chapter 6 and 7 discuss the ideologies of Lewis Mumfold and Chandi Prasad Bhatt. Like the whole book, these chapters are written with a personal lyricism ad lead into Chapter 8 The Democratic Social ecology of Madhav Gadgil, where the idea of social justice finds solace, both in the man himself and the chapter. This was certainly the most agreeable part of the book. The crux of Gadgil’s ideology being the harmony between: ecology, equity and efficiency! Democratic indeed! The concluding chapter is one that book’s title is namesake for. Examining the contemporary society’s “preoccupation with production and productivity,” he juxtaposes it with the idea of possible consequences for the environment if India or China takes to it as has the West. From Gandhi to Galbraith, the critique of “indefinite multiplicity of wants,” is justly put sans environmental romanticism.

Summing it up, the books ends on a question that will dominate our times and the inherent pragmatism in Guha’s writing is one of the major strengths of this book. Free of any utopian imagination, the scholarly suggestions for policy problems in most chapters are not a la mode in writings on environmental causes. Totally, worth reading!

Commercializing Tiger Production

Sometime back in my Economics class Dr. Gordon asked me for my views on “Who will save the Tiger? India or China?” The conversation died within a minute with my ignorance and Dr. Gordon quoting Indira Gandhi: “Poverty is our biggest pollutant/pollution.” (Tried googling it without much luck, so I might be confusing the form of the word, but I have read it before and know this to have been said).




The idea that he was proposing for discussion was which has the greater likelihood of success: animal preserve which is a piece of land with restricted property rights or commerce with clearly defined property rights, which is a point in making with China’s tiger policy. I haven’t read much on China’s policy but it is along the lines of opening up a market for tiger preservation by letting people breed them. An example of successful breeding and also ‘saving from extinction’ is Bison under the auspices of Ted Turner. Idea being as long as there is a market for bison meat people will breed bisons and they will not go extinct. In words of Dr. Gordon “ As long as I can pick up my Bison Burgers from Trader Joe's, I know bisons are safe.” The optimistic faith of an economist in the omnipotent market!

A couple of points before I proceed:

1. India’s preserves (akin to the idea of wilderness preserves in USA) are controlled by Ministry of Environment & Forest, which exercises its jurisdiction on about 20% Indian land with clearly defined property rights.

2. Not so much as wildlife preserves, but the Indian forests are a mighty corporate organization run inefficiently, and a legacy of the British Raj which set it up for motives that were completely market driven, cheap timber may be the keyword here. Had I not been mellowed down by the Economic Thinking (ET) class, I would have used the words like: capitalist, imperialists, exploitative!

3. One of the biggest market for poached Indian tigers is China (if not the largest).

So who will succeed?

From ET lenses, it seems that opening up the preservation to commercial interest would be a good idea. People can make money off raising tigers, people will raise them. There are rules to be followed while doing this, enforceable rules, people will follow them. Thus, there being property tights defined, conflicts will be minimized.

But, isn’t there a market for poached tigers and wasn’t there money to be made in killing tigers? That too incurring hardly any marginal cost for killing every next. I don’t think the poacher is smart enough (just by virtue of being one) or an economic thinker. If he did figure that by killing the next tiger he just decreased his chance of finding the next one, thus increasing his time and effort, he would attribute it as an externality! He would go on as long as there is good money to be made. Also, the low opportunity cost as the risk of being caught was probably low, and he was otherwise unemployed if not a profession poacher. Those are his marketable skills.

But coming back to the question of who will succeed? Either both or at least India!

Assuming market succeeds first and China is exporting tiger bone mix to dollar stores (or Trader Joe's shelves), the biggest market for poached tigers collapses! In fact, the whole poached market collapses (assuming it is highly unlikely that embargoes are successfully imposed on import by poacher lobbies) Tigers are safe in their preserves and outside.

Assuming commercialization approach in China doesn’t take off, situation is as is today. Preservations in India, with clear property rights, enforce better day by day (as other wise they will go out of business if there are no tigers left to save) to keep the salaries coming to those employed. Things get tougher for poachers, cost are way to up. They close business. Everyone works for remuneration, tangible or non-tangible! Tigers saved!

Oh yeah, what if by the time commercialization in China succeeds preservations are wiped clean of paw marks? Impossible. That is where strict Government Policy comes in which will be sufficiently lobbied for by environmentalist of all kinds (tree huggers, wilderness lovers, shallow and deep ecologists, and aerosol researchers and tiger lovers like me). Competition would be too immense for the unorganized poaching industry. Wouldn’t they wish they had trade unions?

P.S. Title says production as it would hardly be procreation when commercialized.

The image has been taken from malayantiger.net